The Political Economy Of Saving The Planet. An Interview With Noam Chomsky & Robert Pollin

Noam Chomsky ~ Photo: en.wikipedia.org

What needs to be done to advance a successful political mobilization on behalf of a global Green New Deal—a program that includes emissions reductions, expands renewable energy sources, addresses the needs of vulnerable workers, and promotes sustainable and egalitarian economic growth? Political scientist C. J. Polychroniou spoke with Noam Chomsky and economist Robert Pollin, who has been at the forefront of the fight for an egalitarian green economy for more than a decade, to discuss prospects for change, the connections between climate and the COVID-19 pandemic, and whether eco-socialism is a viable option for mobilizing people in the struggle to create a green future.

This conversation was adapted from Chomsky and Pollin’s new book Climate Crisis and the Global Green New Deal: The Political Economy of Saving the Planet.

C. J. Polychroniou: How does the coronavirus pandemic, and the response to it, shed light on how we should think about climate change and the prospects for a global Green New Deal?

Noam Chomsky: At the time of writing, concern for the COVID-19 crisis is virtually all-consuming. That’s understandable. It is severe and is severely disrupting lives. But it will pass, though at horrendous cost, and there will be recovery. There will not be recovery from the melting of the arctic ice sheets and the other consequences of global warming.

Not everyone is ignoring the advancing existential crisis. The sociopaths dedicated to accelerating the disaster continue to pursue their efforts, relentlessly. As before, Trump and his courtiers take pride in leading the race to destruction. As the United States was becoming the epicenter of the pandemic, thanks in no small measure to their folly, the White House cabal released its budget proposals. As expected, the proposals call for even deeper cuts in healthcare support and environmental protection, instead favoring the bloated military and the building of Trump’s Great Wall. And to add an extra touch of sadism, the budget promotes a fossil fuel ‘energy boom’ in the United States, including an increase in the production of natural gas and crude oil.”

Robert Pollin

Meanwhile, to drive another nail in the coffin that Trump and associates are preparing for the nation and the world, their corporate-run EPA weakened auto emission standards, thus enhancing environmental destruction and killing more people from pollution. As expected, fossil fuel companies are lining up in the forefront of the appeals of the corporate sector to the nanny state, pleading once again for the generous public to rescue them from the consequences of their misdeeds.

In brief, the criminal classes are relentless in their pursuit of power and profit, whatever the human consequences. And those consequences will be disastrous if their efforts are not countered, indeed overwhelmed, by those concerned for “the survival of humanity.” It is no time to mince words out of misplaced politeness. “The survival of humanity” is at risk on our present course, to quote a leaked internal memo from JPMorgan Chase, America’s largest bank, referring specifically to the bank’s genocidal policy of funding fossil fuel production.

One heartening feature of the present crisis is the rise in community organizations starting mutual aid efforts. These could become centers for confronting the challenges that are already eroding the foundations of the social order. The courage of doctors and nurses, laboring under miserable conditions imposed by decades of socioeconomic lunacy, is a tribute to the resources of the human spirit. There are ways forward. The opportunities cannot be allowed to lapse.

Robert Pollin: In addition to the fundamental considerations that Noam has emphasized, there are several other ways in which the climate crisis and the coronavirus pandemic intersect. One underlying cause of the COVID-19 outbreak—as well as other recent epidemics such as Ebola, West Nile, and HIV—has been the destruction of animal habitats through deforestation and human encroachment, as well as the disruption of the remaining habitat through the increasing frequency and severity of heat waves, droughts, and floods. As the science journalist Sonia Shah wrote in February 2020, habitat destruction increases the likelihood that wild species “will come into repeated intimate contact with the human settlements expanding into their newly fragmented habitats. It’s this kind of repeated, intimate contact that allows the microbes that live in their bodies to cross over into ours, transforming benign animal microbes into deadly human pathogens.”

It is also likely that people who are exposed to dangerous levels of air pollution will face more severe health consequences than those breathing cleaner air. Aaron Bernstein of Harvard’s Center for Climate, Health, and the Global Environment states that “air pollution is strongly associated with people’s risk of getting pneumonia and other respiratory infections and with getting sicker when they do get pneumonia. A study done on SARS, a virus closely related to COVID-19, found that people who breathed dirtier air were about twice as likely to die from the infection.”

A separate point that was raised over the worst months of the COVID-19 pandemic was that the responses in the countries that immediately handled the crisis more effectively, such as South Korea, Taiwan, and Singapore, demonstrated that governments are capable of taking decisive and effective action in the face of crisis. The death tolls from COVID-19 in these countries were negligible, and normal life returned relatively soon after governments imposed initial lockdowns. Similarly decisive interventions could successfully deal with the climate crisis where the political will is strong and the public sectors are competent.

There are important elements of truth in such views, but we should also be careful to not push this point too far. Some commentators have argued that one silver lining outcome of the pandemic was that, because of the economic lockdown, fossil fuel consumption and CO2 emissions plunged alongside overall economic activity during the recession. While this is true, I do not see any positive lessons here with respect to advancing a viable emissions program that can get us to net zero emissions by 2050. Rather, the experience demonstrates why a degrowth approach to emissions reduction is unworkable. Emissions did indeed fall sharply because of the pandemic and the recession. But that is only because incomes collapsed and unemployment spiked over this same period. This only reinforces the conclusion that the only effective climate stabilization path is the Green New Deal, as it is the only one that does not require a drastic contraction (or “degrowth”) of jobs and incomes to drive down emissions.

Read more

Bookmark and Share

Climate Change Intensifies Inequality: An Interview With Gregor Semieniuk

Gregor Semieniuk

This is part of PERI’s economist interview series, hosted by C.J. Polychroniou.

Read Gregor’s bio here.

C.J. Polychroniou: You studied International Relations in Germany, at the Technische Universität Dresden, but ended up pursuing graduate studies in economics in the USA. What drew you into the “dismal science?”

Gregor Semieniuk: In Dresden, the program’s content spanned economics, public law and political science. What intrigued me about economics was that on the one hand it seemed necessary to grapple with the most intractable global issues of the time: for instance, why it was so difficult to increase most countries’ material affluence, how renewable energy could quickly replace the existing energy supply, and of course how the 2007-08 financial crisis and ensuing economic turmoil could be explained. On the other, my economics classes tended to provide straightforward answers to questions that were obviously more multi-faceted, like that a minimum wage was (categorically) to be discouraged because it diminished welfare. From my political science classes I knew that it was good practice to seek out contending theories to analyze the same problem through different lenses so as to gain a deeper understanding. I wanted to learn about contending theories also in economics, but there seemed to be only one theory, so-called neoclassical economics, and its strengths and weaknesses weren’t explicitly discussed. My search for a program that satisfied my curiosity led me to look to the USA, and ultimately to the New School for Social Research, with its famous teaching of a plurality of theoretical approaches. So I went there for my graduate studies. Of course, one thing I learned soon enough was that neoclassical economics and its offshoots can be more nuanced in their assumptions and conclusions. Yet, this does not replace the more variegated approaches and points of analytical departure that the full gamut of ideas in economics (in history and present) has to offer.

CJP: Your primary research areas are in environmental and ecological economics and in economic growth. Can you briefly spell out the connection between climate change and the economy? And, more specifically, in what ways does climate change threaten economic stability and growth?

GS: Climate change is driven by greenhouse gas emissions, that are mainly caused by combusting fossil fuels and from changes in land use (think intensive agriculture or deforestation). Fossil fuels in particular have been historically tightly interlinked with economic growth. Their qualities and quantities are arguably a key factor behind the industrial revolutions in today’s rich countries. Luckily, however, while energy is a fundamental input into any economic activity, there are increasingly good alternatives to fossil fuels to supply that energy without or with much lower emissions, such as modern solar and wind energy, and a growing variety of devices compatible with the electricity they supply, such as electric vehicles and heat pumps.

At an abstract level, the interaction of economic growth and greenhouse gas emissions can be thought of as economic growth causing greenhouse gas emissions to rise. The resulting climate change “dampens” or eventually reverses economic growth through negative impacts on productivity, profitability, capital stock and human lives. More concretely, climate change poses difficult problems and threatens human wellbeing and livelihood in many ways. There are direct impacts, such as lower agricultural productivity or sea level rises. More indirect impacts intensify social problems and conflicts. To give you one example, up to two thirds of Bangladesh’s population are at risk of being impacted by sea level rise by the mid-21st century. This does not mean permanent inundation but increased exposure to flooding and salinity that make it harder to earn a living on agriculture, or risks destroying coastal non-agricultural production sites and homes. The resulting increased migration from coastal to inland communities can exacerbate social conflicts and urban poverty there, ultimately threatening social and economic stability. In the USA, up to 40 million people could be exposed to such hazards by 2100.[1] Of course, here there are much more resources available that could be used to protect communities from these impacts, so the context in which climate change impacts occur matters.

Read more

Bookmark and Share

Isabella Marie Weber – The Peculiarities Of China’s Economic Model

Isabella Weber – PERI Research Associate and Research Leader in China Studies; Assistant Professor of Economics

This is part of PERI’s economist interview series, hosted by C.J. Polychroniou. The Series: https://www.peri.umass.edu/peri-economist-interview-series 

Read Isabella Weber’s bio here. 

C.J. Polychroniou: How did you get into economics? 

Isabella Maria Weber: I got into economics through my interest in politics, in particular global questions. I realized that the political is inherently economic and the economic inherently political. If we want to understand how we can work towards positive change politically, we have to understand the material foundations of our society. If we want to make sense of the major shifts in our global political system, we have to understand the long-term economic dynamics. Coming from this angle, economics for me must take the form of political economy.

CJP:  What do you consider to be the main issue in your research?

IMW: The broad question that motivates my research is how we can make sense of the major changes in the global economy that are unfolding in front of our eyes – at a dramatically accelerated pace since the COVID-19 pandemic. Since the Industrial Revolution in the late 18thcentury, we have lived in a world of a globalizing capitalist economic system, first under British than under U.S. hegemony. This phase is coming to a close with the gradual rise of China – not necessarily to one of dominance but to a more eye-level position. In my research, I pursue two related questions that aim to make a small contribution to this broad challenge: First, I have studied the intellectual foundations behind China’s economic reforms that set the country on the path of its current ascent. Second, I am leading a research project in which we examine the long-term evolution of global export patterns across the last and present era of globalization. The aim here is to understand path dependency and path defiance in the global division of labor. This theme grew out of earlier work on the US-China trade imbalance. In a third strand of my research, I have been investigating foundational questions of the nature of money and the driving forces of international trade for the purpose of placing my work on firmer theoretical grounds.

CJP: Why did you choose to specialize on the Chinese economy?

IMW: I am answering your questions as we watch the global economy collapse under the threat of COVID-19. There is no question that the political and economic power relations between the U.S. and China are changing. Many people in the U.S. and Europe alike are reacting to this uncertain dynamic with fear and, unfortunately, with increasingly racist, anti-Chinese sentiments. In order to work toward a peaceful navigation of the deep structural changes in the world economy, I believe that there is an urgent need for a better understanding of the logic of China’s political economy. Instead of measuring China’s system against the European or American experiences or some standard economics model, we need to study China’s path on its own grounds, while taking into account at the same time its global connectedness. I have specialized in the Chinese economy for the very purpose of making some kind of a contribution to this project.

CJP: How real is the so-called Chinese economic miracle? 

IMW: The Oxford English Dictionary defines a “miracle” as a “marvelous event not ascribable to human power.” China’s economic development of the last four decades is certainly astonishing and as such marvelous. But it is by no means the result of some overnight wonder created by supernatural agency or luck. According to Maddison estimates of 2001, China accounted for about one third of the world’s GDP in 1850. Its share had fallen to below 5 percent in 1950, when China was one of the poorest countries in the world. Today China is responsible for about a fifth of the world’s GDP. These are rough measures, but the trend is obvious. China’s Communist revolution was about much higher aspirations than economic development. But it was clear from the beginning that industrialization and higher living standards were core requirements. Of course, China gave up long ago on Mao’s vision of revolution. But the pursuit of economic progress has continued across dramatically different political phases since 1949. China’s gradual return to a more prominent position in the world economy is not the result of a miracle, but of decades of hard work and heterodox economic policymaking. In a forthcoming book of mine, I argue that China’s economic leaders learned key lessons from the history of economic warfare in the 1930s and 1940s. At the heart of this strategy is the articulation of clear broad goals which are being pursued by flexibly utilizing prevailing economic dynamics and structures.

CJP: How did China manage to liberalize its economy while avoiding shock therapy, which is pretty much what happened in virtually all transition economies in Eastern Europe, Russia, and Latin America?  

IMW: We often imagine of China’s gradual economic reforms as having been without an alternative. In fact, the 1980s marked a crossroads in the recent history of China and of global capitalism, as I show in my forthcoming book “How China Escaped Shock Therapy.” China too had very concrete plans for far-ranging overnight liberalizations. Had China implemented the policy of “shock therapy,” it would most likely have generated the same devastating results that we have observed elsewhere, but on a much larger scale. China would have mirrored Russia’s fall, but starting from a much lower level.

The basic premise of shock therapy is that all institutions of direct state control over the economy must be destroyed to make space for the market. Instead, China pursued a strategy of market creation that utilized the institutions of the planned economy. It kept the core of the planned industrial economy working, while transforming the old institutions into market players by first allowing for market activities on the margins. This strategy is manifested in the dual-track price system. Under this system, state-owned enterprises and farmers had to deliver the state-set quotas at a state-set price, but if they managed to produce more, they could market their surplus at market prices. In this way, China’s economy was gradually marketized under active bureaucratic guidance by reorienting its core economic institutions from the plan to the market. Non-essentials were liberalized first. Surpluses as well as sectors producing non-basic goods were non-essentials. They could be completely marketized without immediately endangering the stability of the whole system. Yet, the marketization of these non-essential areas unleashed a dynamic that fundamentally transformed the whole political economy, including its core.[1] As a result of this strategy, China kept much closer control over core sectors of the economy, such as energy, steel, finance and infrastructure. This has allowed China to respond in a fine-grained and targeted way to the 2008 global financial crisis, and to the current economic collapse in light of COVID-19.

CJP: Could/should the Chinese model be emulated by other developing countries?  

IMW: China had a very different starting point from most other developing countries today. From a longue durée perspective, China could build on a very long history of bureaucratic market creation and participation. Tools derived from the statecraft of playing the market were utilized during the revolutionary struggles and again in the reform era. Considering the more immediate context, the Mao era had laid strong foundations for China’s take off in terms of education, literacy, public health and basic industrialization. Most developing countries do not have those preconditions. It would therefore not make sense to simply copy China’s model. But there is a deeper reason for not copying China’s model that emerges from China’s own experience. It is extremely important to realize that China, too, did not simply copy foreign models. Chinese researchers and officials, in collaboration with international partners, studied carefully the experience of various other countries and drew lessons for the country’s own specific situation, adapting the insights to its concrete conditions, often with major problems in the process. This approach of careful study of the prevailing local condition and adaptation of foreign experiences is what other developing countries can learn from China. But there is no panacea that works for all. The Beijing Model should not replace the Washington Consensus. The lesson is that there is no easy universal solution, no policy package that can fix it all.

CJP: What’s your view on Trump’s trade war with China? More generally, do you think the Chinese economy poses threats to the U.S. economy and other countries’ economies? If so, should they do anything about it?

IMW: I think that the trade war is an extremely dangerous policy. If any further proof was needed – and I don’t think there is, COVID-19 is demonstrating in a morbid fashion just how closely integrated the world is with China, and vice versa.  In the 1980s China retreated from its revolutionary ambitions and embarked on a path of reform using its state capacity to reintegrate into the global market. Since the 1990s, we have been living through a second peak of globalization in modern times. The last globalization ended with the First World War. The present one is collapsing as I am writing. In such a situation, we need international collaboration, not war of any kind. I don’t think the Chinese economy, taken by itself, poses a threat to the U.S. or to other countries. Crises of this historical moment don’t have a nationality; they lie in the nature of the global system. The real threat results from the exploitation of this crisis by nationalists and racists. To confront this threat, we have to improve our understanding of China, instead of feeding into scapegoat narratives.

Reference:
[1] I spell this out in greater detail in this interview: https://www.peri.umass.edu/economists/isabella/item/1206-the-making-of-china-s-economic-reforms

Bookmark and Share

Utopia en omstreken: imaginaire gebieden

Behalve fictieve personen, zoals Anton Steenwijk en Josef K., David Copperfield en Nathan Sid, heeft de literatuur ook fictieve steden en landen opgeleverd. Lewis Carroll liet Alice haar avonturen beleven in Wonderland, Jonathan Swift stuurde Lemuel Gulliver in Gulliver’s Travels (1726) onder meer naar Lilliput, Brobdingnag, Lagado, Glubbdubrib en Houyhnhnmland.
J.R.R. Tolkien creëerde voor de In de ban van de ring-cyclus (1954-1955) zelfs een hele mythologie, inclusief landkaarten en taal, rond Middle-earth. Dat leverde welluidende namen op als Esgalduin, Nanduhirion, Angrenost en Nimrodel.

En zoals sommige fictieve personages, zoals de Jan en Erik in het werk van Wolkers, de Gerard in dat van Reve en de Maarten in dat van ‘t Hart, dicht in de buurt van het levende voorbeeld blijven, zo is in sommige van die fictieve gebieden zonder veel moeite de woonomgeving van de auteur te herkennen.

De Amerikaanse schrijver William Faulkner, geboren in de zuidelijke staat Mississippi, situeert een deel van zijn romans in het niet-bestaande Yoknapatawpha County, een streek in het noorden van Mississippi. En het Lahringen uit Vestdijks Anton Wachter-romans ligt wel erg dicht bij het Harlingen waar de schrijver geboren werd.

Maar een groot deel van die steden, streken en landen zijn speciaal voor het literaire werk bedacht en in het register van niet één atlas terug te vinden. Nou, drie dan: in de Amerikaanse Dictionary of Imaginary Places (1980), in Umberto Eco’s De geschiedenis van imaginaire landen en plaatsen (2013) en in de Atlas van imaginaire landen (2016) van Dominique Lanni.

The Shangri-Las

Het aardige is dat die bedachte plaatsen soms een eigen leven zijn gaan leiden. Een mooi voorbeeld daarvan is Shangri-La, de lusthof in de roman Lost horizon (1933) van de Engelse schrijver James Hilton. Shangri-La, dat vermoedelijk ergens in Tibet ligt, is synoniem geworden met ‘paradijselijk oord’ en liet in die betekenis veel sporen na in de popmuziek. In de jaren vijftig ontstond in Amerika de meisjesgroep The Shangri-Las, die, behalve om hun suikerspinkapsels en zuurstokkleurige strechtbroeken, bekend werden met o.a. Remember (walking in the sand) en I can never go home anymore. The Kinks hadden in 1969 een hit met Shangri-La, de Nederlandse Elvis Presley, Jack Jersey, zette het bijna onuitspreekbare Sri Lanka, My Shangri-La op de plaat en in 1988 vertegenwoordigde Gerard Joling ons land op het Eurovisie Songfestival met Ik wil terug naar Shangri-La.
En om in de popmuziek te blijven: Xanadu, dat in 1968 de kleurrijke Britse groep Dave Dee, Dozy, Beaky, Mick & Titch inspireerde tot The legend of Xanadu en in 1980 een hit opleverde voor Olivia Newton-John, stamt uit het (onvoltooid gebleven) gedicht ‘Kubla Khan’ van de Engelse poëet Samuel Taylor Coleridge (1772-1834), waarvan de eerste regels luiden: In Xanadu did Kubla Khan a stately pleasure-dome decree. Het moet waarschijnlijk in China gezocht worden, niet ver van Shangri-La. En ook het enorme landhuis van Charles Foster Kane in de film Citizen Kane (1941) van Orson Welles heet Xanadu.

Een vervolg van geheel andere orde kreeg Thule. Dat is de naam die in de klassieke oudheid gegeven werd aan een eiland dat zes dagen zeilen ten noorden van Schotland heette te liggen en dat als het einde van de wereld beschouwd werd. Sommige schrijvers zagen IJsland er voor aan, andere Shetland of zelfs de kust van Noorwegen. Het werd vooral bekend in de uitdrukking Ultima Thule – ‘het einde van de wereld’ – en komt in die zin al voor bij de Romeinse schrijvers Virgilius en Seneca.
In navolging van chemische elementen als berkelium en ytterbium, die hun naam kregen van de plaats waar ze gevormd werden (respectievelijk Berkeley in Californië en Ytterby in Zweden), dankt thulium zijn naam aan Thule. Het moet het enige chemische element zijn dat naar een niet-bestaande plaats vernoemd is, al gebiedt de volledigheid te wijzen op het element thorium, genoemd naar een fictieve figuur, de Germaanse dondergod Thor.

Het bekendste literaire land is waarschijnlijk Utopia (1516), het droomeiland uit het gelijknamige werk van Thomas More waar de ideale maatschappij zetelt. De naam is opgebouwd uit twee Griekse woorden, ou (niet) en topos (plaats), en kan dus vertaald worden met ‘Nergensland’. Het is niet alleen het bekendste, ook het invloedrijkste. Utopia komt ook voor in andere literaire werken – in Rabelais’ Gargantua en Pantagruel (1532-1564), bijvoorbeeld, waarin de laatste van deze twee reuzen het eiland bezoekt – en heeft een heuse utopische stroming in de literatuur op gang gebracht, met alle namen van dien. Daaronder valt Shangri-La, alsook het Oceana uit James Harringtons The Commonwealth of Oceana (1656) en het Macaria (letterlijk: Zaligland) van de Duitser Caspar Stiblinus.

Maar er ontstond ook een stroming tegen al dat idealisme, en zo ontstond het begrip ‘distopia’.
Zo’n anti-utopia werd onder meer uitgewerkt door Samuel Butler, die zijn visie op de zorgenvrije gemeenschap geeft in Erewhon (1872), een anagram van nowhere. En ene E. Callenbach publiceerde in 1975 Ecotopia, waarin de overindustrialisatie van onze maatschappij wordt bekritiseerd (eco stamt van het Griekse oikos – ‘huis(gezin), familie’ – en komt tegenwoordig veel voor in samenstellingen die op het milieu betrekking hebben, zoals ecosysteem en ecotax).
Ook in de Nederlandse letteren zijn fictieve plaatsen geschapen. De Zwolse chirurgijn Hendrik Smeeks beschreef een imaginaire reis in Beschryvinge van het Magtig Koninkryk Krinke Kesmes (1708). Mooi zijn ook de twee namen in Simon Stijls toneelstuk De Torenbouw van het Vlek Brikkekiks in het landschap Batrachia (1787), een satire op de aanhouding van prinses Wilhelmina bij Goejanverwellesluis in dat jaar. Batrachia betekent ‘Kikkerland’ en in die context is Brikkekiks te interpreteren als kikkergekwaak.

De strijd tussen patriotten en orangisten speelde een rol in Reize door het Aapenland (1788), dat op naam staat van J.A. Schasz, M.D. Het is, net als bijvoorbeeld Gulliver’s Travels, een satirisch imaginair reisverhaal, een genre dat hem blijkbaar goed beviel, want hij schreef ook Reize door het Wonderland (1780) en Reize door het Land der Vrijwillige Slaaven (1790).
Belcampo geeft een beeld van de wereld in het jaar 12.000 in zijn verhaal Voorland (1935), maar de aardigste in het Nederlands komen van de dichter Jean Pierre Rawie. Die woont in Groningen, maar hij wil daar in de datering van zijn brieven nog wel eens op variëren. In het door Boudewijn Buch samengestelde promotieboekje Buch Boeket 1 begint een brief van Rawie aan zijn uitgever met ‘Gromsk II IX MCMLXXXV’. Later verstuurde hij ook wel brieven vanuit Groomsbury, waarin behalve Groningen ook Bloomsbury doorklinkt, de kunstenaarswijk in Londen waaraan de Bloomsbury-groep rond Virginia en Leonard Woolf en Lytton Strachey haar naam ontleent.

Mijn persoonlijke voorkeur gaat uit naar Lake Wobegon, het bescheiden plaatsje – smalltown in het Amerikaans – in de Amerikaanse staat Minnesota waar Garrison Keillor zijn Lake Wobegon Days (1985) gesitueerd heeft. Niet alleen omdat ik het persoonlijk bezocht heb (wat bij mijn weten de enige keer geweest is, dat ik in een fictief gebied liep), maar ook omdat er zo’n mooie vertaling van bestaat. In het Wobegon-meer waarnaar het dorp is genoemd, is zonder veel moeite de uitdrukking wo(e)begone te herkennen: treurig, somber, naargeestig, getroffen, bezocht.
Omdat Lake Wobegon niet ver onder de grens met het tweetalige Canada ligt, heeft het ook een Franse naam. Onder verwijzing naar Lac Majeur staat het neerslachtige oord ook bekend als Lac Malheur.


Robert-Henk Zuidinga (1949) studeerde Nederlandse en Engelse Moderne Letterkunde aan de Universiteit van Amsterdam. Hij schrijft over literatuur, taal- en bij uitzondering – over film.
De drie delen Dit staat er bevatten de, volgens zijn eigen omschrijving, journalistieke nalatenschap van Zuidinga. De boeken zijn in eigen beheer uitgegeven. Belangstelling? Stuur een berichtje naar: info@rozenbergquarterly.com– wij sturen uw bericht door naar de auteur.
Dit staat er 1. Columns over taal en literatuur. Haarlem 2016. ISBN 9789492563040
Dit staat er II, Artikelen en interviews over literatuur. Haarlem 2017. ISBN 9789492563248
Dit staat er III. Bijnamen en Nederlied. Buitenlied en film, Haarlem 2019. ISBN 97894925636637

Bookmark and Share

Elif Shafak – Zo houd je moed in een tijd van verdeeldheid

Elif Shafak – Ills.: Joseph Sassoon Semah

Hoe kunnen we hoop, vertrouwen en geloof in een betere wereld voeden in een wereld die voelt alsof-ie op instorten staat, waar ontgoocheling en verbijstering heerst en we niet worden gehoord? Door de pandemie maken we nu een betekeniscrisis mee: fundamentele concepten moeten worden geherdefinieerd. De democratie is veel fragieler dan we dachten: ze is een delicaat ecosysteem van checks-and-balances dat voortdurend voeding en verzorging behoeft, aldus Elif Shafak.

Elif Shafak gelooft in de kracht van verhalen om te laten zien hoe democratie, tolerantie en vooruitgang door schrijven kunnen worden gevoed. Zij is geboren in Frankrijk, groeide op in Turkije, Spanje en de Verenigde Staten, en is nu staatsburger van het Verenigd Koninkrijk, maar leeft vooral in ‘Verhalenland’.
Als romanschrijfster voelt ze zich aangetrokken door verhalen en door stiltes. Haar aandacht is vooral gefocust op de ‘periferie’, de gemarginaliseerde, achtergestelde, rechteloze en gecensureerde stemmen. En op taboes: politieke, culturele en gendertaboes, want als we niet luisteren naar afwijkende meningen, stoppen we met leren.
Groepsdenken of sociale mediabubbels voeden en versterken de herhaling. Daarom moeten we blijven bewegen, intellectuele nomaden worden, tijd doorbrengen aan de randen van de samenleving.

De mensen zijn ontgoocheld doordat hun stem niet wordt gehoord, worden geconfronteerd met een politiek systeem dat bestaat uit marketingsteksten, een financiële markt die wordt gedreven door hebzucht en winst, recente gebeurtenissen die niet meer verlopen op de lineaire progressieve manier zoals eerder. Mensen zijn verbijsterd doordat kunstmatige intelligentie en data steeds meer invloed krijgen, zonder dat gewacht wordt totdat het menselijk verstand het kan bevatten. Wat rest is een grote leegte, een onzeker bestaan en een onbekend en onvoorspelbaar begin, waar we helemaal alleen zijn, zonder dat we deel uit maken van een collectief. We zijn ongerust over de toestand van de wereld, en onze plaats daarin, of juist gebrek aan een eigen plaats. We hebben een voortdurende onrust, een existentiële angst, we zijn kwetsbaar. We zijn bezorgd en boos. Hoe kunnen we die individuele en collectieve woede omzetten in een positieve kracht en betrokken zijn? En niet apathisch zijn waardoor we geïsoleerd raken.

Het staat voor Elif Shafak vast dat we niet kunnen terugkeren naar de situatie van voor de pandemie. We hebben de keuze tussen het nationalisme, de ‘eigen volk eerst’-benadering of de weg naar internationale communicatie en samenwerking. De keuze is afhankelijk van economische en politieke factoren, maar ook van het debat over identiteit. Hoe we onze identiteit benaderen zal onze volgende stappen bepalen, aldus Shafak. Zij definieert zichzelf als een wereldburger, een universele ziel, burger van de hele mensheid. We moeten allemaal geëngageerde, betrokken burgers worden. Verhalen kunnen ons daarbij helpen, ze leveren een genuanceerder, reflectievere manier om te beschouwen, ervaren, voelen en herinneren. Ze geven inzicht in de complexiteit en rijkdom van identiteiten, en van de schade die we aanrichten als we die proberen te reduceren tot één enkel definiërend kenmerk. Verhalen hebben een herscheppende kracht om ‘mensen samen te brengen, onze cognitieve horizon te verbreden, en langzaam maar zeker meer empathie en wijsheid te ontwikkelen’.

Elif Shafak – Zo houd je moed in een tijd van verdeeldheid. Uitgeverij Nieuw Amsterdam, 2020. 96 pag. ISBN9789046828151

Elif Shafak schrijft in het Engels en Turks. Haar werk is in vijftig talen vertaald en won diverse internationale prijzen.

Elif Shafak – The revolutionary power of diverse thought

“From populist demagogues, we will learn the indispensability of democracy,” says novelist Elif Shafak. “From isolationists, we will learn the need for global solidarity. And from tribalists, we will learn the beauty of cosmopolitanism” A native of Turkey, Shafak has experienced firsthand the devastation that a loss of diversity can bring — and she knows the revolutionary power of plurality in response to authoritarianism. In this passionate, personal talk, she reminds us that there are no binaries, in politics, emotions and our identities. “One should never, ever remain silent for fear of complexity,” Shafak says.

Check out more TED Talks: http://www.ted.com

Linda Bouws – St. Metropool Internationale Kunstprojecten

Bookmark and Share

‘Limits’ Of Imagining The Pandemic Present

Michel Foucault 1926 – 1984  Photo: wikipedia.org

In 1984, Michel Foucault, the French historian (or) philosopher, associated with the  structuralist (or) post-structuralist movement, extensively commented [i] on the German Philosopher Immanuel Kant’s ‘Was ist Aufklarung?’ (What is Enlightenment?). Thus, two hundred years hence, Foucault knocked at the limits of moments we live through. For him, Kant is responding in the Berlinische Monatsschrift (Berlin monthly, 1784- November), a late enlightenment mouthpiece, on what should be the attitude to present.

The moment we live in was, for Kant, neither a distinct era, not a transition, but rather a grand exit (Ausgang). For Kant majority of human beings, in the time he wrote in (1700s end or 1800s beginning as the case may be), carried on their everyday life with the church and monarchy setting the rhythms. The autonomy to break the rhythm or to think about the present, and thus make the exit, was difficult then, as it is now. For Foucault Kant was to work on the ‘limits’ of the rhythm and the everyday in order to ‘Ausgang’ and reflect on what he was part of.

With the coordinates of daily rhythms overwhelmingly set by the virus and its trajectories, it has become even tougher to separate ourselves from the contingent contexts we are thrown into everyday. The possibility of thinking separate from the frames we are set against, and reflecting on our ‘makes’, will determine not only how we reflect on the times we live in, but also the way we live out.

People across space and time have transformed to cyborgs – the sciences; technological artifacts; institutional orders; as well as disseminations of knowledge literally imbricate lived lives. Risk societies, urban informalities, everyday precarities, techno-social deployments, or surveillance and pastoral orders have scaled our skins and rewired our bodily rhythms. The cyborg identities in their everyday relationship with other cyborgs, with differential make-ups determine the truth orders that govern.
Foucault comes back to haunt the ‘pandemic orders in the making’ prompting an engagement with the limits. Nothing short of a critical ontology of the cyborgs we are, deployed and networked across space and time, by the political every day, can achieve this. Only this can translate into a possibility or impossibility to imagine the limits that are imposed on us by the political systems, exaggerated by the pandemic.

The possibility of knocking at the limits for instance, might come at best as a tragic reflection during the physical ejection of the urban migrant labourer in India from the metropolis. This is not quite an exit and neither does one see the space or time to reflect on the exploitative order that had appropriated him/her along with millions of others as urban cyborgs. A Lebanese Druze leader who has seen the end of a world war, been through a three month war, or the civil wars; still might only see at best an end of the world because the pandemic has only added on to the noise of everyday violence and earth shattering explosions. The fortified corona shelters that the bus bays have transformed into in a hyper vigilant South Korea or a health care regime that fell apart on the corporate altars in the United States also differentially reduce the space of reflection or eventual exit. A self righteous regime like the one in Brazil that would rather bank on military men than people of science; or the celebrations of self sufficiency (atmanirbhar in the Indian state context) when possibilities of social welfare gets precluded; also talk of the times that give no space for exit-thoughts or possibilities for reflection.

In order to critically reflect on the pandemic everyday and eventually for life to live itself out, there is no other way than exposing the conflicts and contradictions inherent to the orders people live in. There is no other way than to reflect on the ‘fixes’ put forward as part of the ‘presents’. Michel Foucault prompts us to knock at the limits once again. The task for the more privileged in places that still maintain social contracts with populations is to think with Foucauldian ‘dispositives’. These are the institutional, administrative, and knowledge structures that both maintain the systems in place and the homeostasis of the cyborg selves we all are. It is only by thinking through the links between practices, and institutional techniques deployed way before pandemics, but enhanced and perpetuated by the virus; that the cyborgs can get deconstructed across places readying for a political present that is yet to be lived into.

Note
[i] What is Enlightenment? in Rabinow (P.), ed., The Foucault Reader, New York, Pantheon Books, 1984:32-50.

Mathew A Varghese, SIRP, Mahatma Gandhi University [Previously Researcher at University of Bergen/ UKZN]

 

Bookmark and Share
image_pdfimage_print

  • About

    Rozenberg Quarterly aims to be a platform for academics, scientists, journalists, authors and artists, in order to offer background information and scholarly reflections that contribute to mutual understanding and dialogue in a seemingly divided world. By offering this platform, the Quarterly wants to be part of the public debate because we believe mutual understanding and the acceptance of diversity are vital conditions for universal progress. Read more...
  • Support

    Rozenberg Quarterly does not receive subsidies or grants of any kind, which is why your financial support in maintaining, expanding and keeping the site running is always welcome. You may donate any amount you wish and all donations go toward maintaining and expanding this website.

    10 euro donation:

    20 euro donation:

    Or donate any amount you like:

    Or:
    ABN AMRO Bank
    Rozenberg Publishers
    IBAN NL65 ABNA 0566 4783 23
    BIC ABNANL2A
    reference: Rozenberg Quarterly

    If you have any questions or would like more information, please see our About page or contact us: info@rozenbergquarterly.com
  • Like us on Facebook

  • Archives